Labor Productivity Increases 2.0% for Q3

The BLS Productivity & Costs report for Q3 2014 shows labor productivity increased 2.0% annualized.  Output increased 4.4% and hours worked increased 2.3%.  Unit Labor costs increased only 0.3% in Q3 2014.  The reason labor productivity rose was because economic output grew more than worker hours.  Overall labor is still getting squeezed for more efficiency and wages are still repressed.  The mediocre Q3 productivity results also imply corporations can rake in the profits and not raise prices.  Below is a graph of the quarterly change in labor productivity.

 

 

The basic equation for labor productivity is:     \small \frac{Q}L,   where \small Q is the total output of industry and \small L stands for labor.

Output can be thought of what is produced from the fruits of labor.  Examples would be the cars which come off the assembly line and burgers & fries being served up at McDonald's.  Here is the BLS labor productivity formula:

Labor productivity is calculated by dividing an index of real output by an index of the combined hours worked of all persons, including employees, proprietors, and unpaid family workers.

\small L, or Labor, is measured in hours only.  Nonfarm Business Output directly correlates to real GDP, minus the government, farms,all of those nonprofits and our infamous, often illegal nannies and gardeners, and equivalent rent of owner occupied properties.   The output, or \small Q is about 74% of real GDP reported.  Farms, if you can believe this, only represent about 1% of output.   Labor productivity is reported as annualized figures and both indexes are normalized to the year 2009.  The main productivity numbers above are all business, no farms, where labor costs have a high ratio, about 60%, to output.  These productivity statistics are referred to as nonfarm business.

From Q3 2013, a year ago, annual productivity increased 0.9%, output increased 3.0%, and hours worked rose by 2.1%.  That is fairly sluggish productivity growth.  Labor productivity changes from a year ago is shown in the below graph.

 

 

BLS defines unit labor costs as the ratio of hourly compensation, to labor productivity, where \small C is compensation \small L represents hours worked as above, or:
   \small \frac{\frac{C}L}{\frac{Q}L} = \frac{C}{Q}
For more formula definitions see the BLS handbook.  One can also view unit labor costs as the ratio of total worker financial compensation to economic output, adjusted for inflation.   Below is the report description of the ratio relationship:

BLS defines unit labor costs as the ratio of hourly compensation to labor productivity; increases in hourly compensation tend to increase unit labor costs and increases in output per hour tend to reduce them. Real hourly compensation is equal to hourly compensation divided by the consumer price series.

Graphed below are unit labor costs, compounded annual rate, percent change.  Nonfarm business Unit labor costs increased by 0.3% for Q3 2014.   From a year ago, Q3 2013, labor costs are up 2.4%.  Decreases in unit labor costs imply compensation is not keeping up with economic output.   Increased productivity, or output per hour, for the same $$ paid to workers would lower unit labor costs.

 

 

Graphed below are unit labor costs, indexed to 2005.  We can see the decline correlating to the Great Recession.   One can also see some recovery in the last three years, but not enough one would have without labor arbitrage.

 

 

Real hourly compensation is wages adjusted for inflation.  Real hourly compensation is equal to hourly compensation, defined above, divided by a special inflation series called the consumer price series*, \small P

\small \frac{\frac{C}L}{P}

In terms of real dollars, adjusted for inflation, we have a 1.2% increase in real hourly compensation for Q3 2014, non-farm businesses.  This is actually some better news for in comparison to the past wages have not kept up with inflation.   In comparison to Q3 2013, real hourly compensation increased 1.4%.  This means wages finally kept up with inflation since 2013.  Below are quarterly changes to hourly compensation, adjusted for consumer prices.

 

 

Below is a historical graph of real hourly compensation for nonfarm business.  What this shows is worker squeeze extensively from 2007 to 2013.  We see a steady increase up until 1980 and then starting with year 2007, we see a complete flat line, until now.  As productivity soars, clearly workers are getting less and less of their share.

 

 

The BLS also reports separately on manufacturing productivity, but uses a different calculation method than the one for business productivity.  Don't think one can subtract manufacturing from business and get services productivity, the two are not the same.  Manufacturing is sales, removing duplicates, adjusting for prices and output (\small Q) is correlated to shipments and the industrial production. indexes.  Hours are hours like above.  The report, p. 5, has the manufacturing productivity measurement details.

Manufacturing productivity increased 3.2%, for Q3 2014.  Manufacturing output grew by 4.1%, while hours worked increased 0.8%.  Since Q3 2013, manufacturing productivity increased 2.8% as output increased by 4.4% and hours worked showed a 1.5% increase.  Over the past year, manufacturing shown some employment growth, so the above correlates to payrolls and the manufacturing ISM indicators.

 

 

Manufacturing unit labor costs decreased -0.7% for Q3 2014.  From Q3 2013, manufacturing unit labor costs have increased by 0.6%.

 

 

Compensation for manufacturing workers increased 2.5 % for the quarter and from a year ago has increased 3.4%.  That's quite an improvement in comparison to past years and quarters.

 

manufacturing hourly compensation

 

Q3 2014 real compensation (wages) in manufacturing grew by 1.4%.   From Q3 2013, real hourly compensation for manufacturing workers at least has increased by 1.6%, which means wages have kept up with inflation.  Manufacturing wages have been under attack previously so this is some better news for workers.

 

 

For Q3 2014, durable good manufacturing productivity grew by 4.2%, output increased 6.6% and hours worked increased by 2.3%.  Durable goods labor unit costs dramatically dropped by -2.2%, compensation increased by 1.8%, which implies real compensation increased by 0.7%.  Graphed below is the durable goods manufacturing real hourly compensation index and marvel at the decline over time.

 

 

Unit labor costs in durable goods shows the decline of the American worker for they are returning to their lows.  Unit labor costs show real output per hour.  Durable goods workers are producing more and more and U.S. workers are getting less reward.

 

 

Nondurable manufacturing productivity increased by 3.0% on an output increase of 1.2%.  Hours declined by -1.8%.  Nondurable manufacturing unit labor costs increased by 0.4%, hourly compensation also increased, 3.5% and real hourly compensation increased by 2.4%.  Nondurable goods might be harder to offshore outsource and the reason we see wages increase.

What you see these days in productivity is not what it appears.  The press will claim increased productivity is a great thing, and maybe that's true for corporate profits, but it's clearly not translating into wages and jobs for workers.  Labor share is a measure of how much of the economic pie goes to workers.  If labor share increases, this implies labor is benefiting from increased economic growth.  When the compensation to productivity gap widens, labor share falls and that means workers are not reaping the economic rewards of their sweat and toil.

Below is labor market share for nonfarm business which shows workers overall are getting less and less of the productivity pie.

 

 

Overall, the labor productivity statistics for Q3 2014 look like the American worker shifted into a very slow improvement mode from past declines.  The better news is the modest productivity increases are due to increased output vs. squeezing employees.

 

 

* The BLS productivity statisticians use CPI-U-RS, an unpublished inflation research metric, for the consumer price series.  This consumer price series seems to flatten inflation, thus make the decline in U.S. wages less, although when normalized to a base year of 2009 the two series are the same for all practical purposes.   The implicit price deflator, applied to nonfarm business output (productivity), is from the BEA.  The CPS and the price deflator are all to remove inflation effects from the productivity statistics.

Subject Meta: 

Forum Categories: